"Larry Summers asks:
How…could our society have regressed
to the point where a bridge that could be built in less than a year one century
ago takes five times as long to repair today?
As I wrote in Launching:
Our ancestors were bold and
industrious–they built a significant portion of our energy and road infrastructure
more than half a century ago. It would be almost impossible to build the system
today. Unfortunately, we cannot rely on the infrastructure of our past to
travel to our future.
Summers alludes to the regulatory
thicket as a cause of the infrastructure slowdown but doesn’t have much to say
about fixing the problem. Here’s a place to begin. Repeal all historic
preservation laws. It’s one thing to require safety permits but no
construction project should require a historic preservation permit. Here are
three reasons:
First, it’s often the case that
buildings of little historical worth are preserved by rules and
regulations that are used as a pretext to slow competitors, maintain
monopoly rents, and keep neighborhoods in a kind of aesthetic stasis that
benefits a small number of people at the expense of many others.Second, a confident nation builds so that future people may look back and marvel at their ancestors ingenuity and aesthetic vision. A nation in decline looks to the past in a vain attempt to “preserve” what was once great. Preservation is what you do to dead butterflies.
Ironically, if today’s rules for
historical preservation had been in place in the past the buildings that some
now want to preserve would never have been built at all. The opportunity
cost of preservation is future greatness.
Third, repealing historic
preservation laws does not mean ending historic preservation. There is a
very simple way that truly great buildings can be preserved–they can be bought
or their preservation rights paid for. The problem with historic preservation
laws is not the goal but the methods. Historic preservation laws attempt
to foist the cost of preservation on those who want to build (very much
including builders of infrastructure such as the government). Attempting
to foist costs on others, however, almost inevitably leads to a system full of
lawyers, lobbying and rent seeking–and that leads to high transaction costs and
delay. Richard Epstein advocated a compensation system for takings because takings
violat ethics and constitutional law. But perhaps an
even bigger virtue of a compensation system is that it’s quick. A building
worth preserving is worth paying to preserve. A compensation system unites
builders and those who want to preserve and thus allows for quick decisions
about what will be preserved and what will not.
Some people will object that
repealing historic preservation laws will lead to some lovely buildings being
destroyed. Of course, it will. There is no point pretending otherwise. It will
also lead to some lovely buildings being created. More generally, however, the
logic of regulatory thickets tells us that we cannot have everything. As I
argued in Launching:
There are good regulations and bad
regulations and lots of debate over which is which. From an innovation
perspective, however, this debate misses a key point. Let’s assume that all regulations
are good. The problem is that even if each regulation is good, the net effect
of all the regulations combined may be bad. A single pebble in a big stream
doesn’t do much, but throw enough pebbles and the stream of innovation
is dammed.
It’s time to blow the dam. Creative
destruction requires some destruction."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.